Set identification
In statistics and econometrics, set identification (or partial identification) extends the concept of identifiability (or "point identification") in statistical models to environments where the model and the distribution of observable variables are not sufficient to determine a unique value for the model parameters, but instead constrain the parameters to lie in a strict subset of the parameter space. Statistical models that are set (or partially) identified arise in a variety of settings in economics, including game theory and the Rubin causal model. Unlike approaches that deliver point-identification of the model parameters, methods from the literature on partial identification are used to obtain set estimates that are valid under weaker modelling assumptions.[1]
History
[edit]Early works containing the main ideas of set identification included Frisch (1934) and Marschak & Andrews (1944). However, the methods were significantly developed and promoted by Charles Manski, beginning with Manski (1989) and Manski (1990).
Partial identification continues to be a major theme in research in econometrics. Powell (2017) named partial identification as an example of theoretical progress in the econometrics literature, and Bonhomme & Shaikh (2017) list partial identification as “one of the most prominent recent themes in econometrics.”
Definition
[edit]Let denote a vector of latent variables, let denote a vector of observed (possibly endogenous) explanatory variables, and let denote a vector of observed endogenous outcome variables. A structure is a pair , where represents a collection of conditional distributions, and is a structural function such that for all realizations of the random vectors . A model is a collection of admissible (i.e. possible) structures .[2][3]
Let denote the collection of conditional distributions of consistent with the structure . The admissible structures and are said to be observationally equivalent if .[2][3] Let denotes the true (i.e. data-generating) structure. The model is said to be point-identified if for every we have . More generally, the model is said to be set (or partially) identified if there exists at least one admissible such that . The identified set of structures is the collection of admissible structures that are observationally equivalent to .[4]
In most cases the definition can be substantially simplified. In particular, when is independent of and has a known (up to some finite-dimensional parameter) distribution, and when is known up to some finite-dimensional vector of parameters, each structure can be characterized by a finite-dimensional parameter vector . If denotes the true (i.e. data-generating) vector of parameters, then the identified set, often denoted as , is the set of parameter values that are observationally equivalent to .[4]
Example: missing data
[edit]This example is due to Tamer (2010). Suppose there are two binary random variables, Y and Z. The econometrician is interested in . There is a missing data problem, however: Y can only be observed if .
By the law of total probability,
The only unknown object is , which is constrained to lie between 0 and 1. Therefore, the identified set is
Given the missing data constraint, the econometrician can only say that . This makes use of all available information.
Statistical inference
[edit]Set estimation cannot rely on the usual tools for statistical inference developed for point estimation. A literature in statistics and econometrics studies methods for statistical inference in the context of set-identified models, focusing on constructing confidence intervals or confidence regions with appropriate properties. For example, a method developed by Chernozhukov, Hong & Tamer (2007) constructs confidence regions that cover the identified set with a given probability.
Notes
[edit]- ^ Tamer 2010.
- ^ a b "Generalized Instrumental Variable Models - The Econometric Society". www.econometricsociety.org. doi:10.3982/ecta12223. Retrieved 2024-01-05.
- ^ a b Matzkin, Rosa L. (2013-08-02). "Nonparametric Identification in Structural Economic Models". Annual Review of Economics. 5 (1): 457–486. doi:10.1146/annurev-economics-082912-110231. ISSN 1941-1383.
- ^ a b Lewbel 2019.
References
[edit]- Bonhomme, Stephane; Shaikh, Azeem (2017). "Keeping the econ in econometrics:(micro-) econometrics in the journal of political economy". The Journal of Political Economy. 125 (6): 1846–1853. doi:10.1086/694620.
- Chernozhukov, Victor; Hong, Han; Tamer, Elie (2007). "Estimation and Confidence Regions for Parameter Sets in Econometric Models". Econometrica. 75 (5). The Econometric Society: 1243–1284. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0262.2007.00794.x. hdl:1721.1/63545. ISSN 0012-9682.
- Frisch, Ragnar (1934). Statistical Confluence Analysis by means of Complete Regression Systems. University Institute of Economics, Oslo.
- Manski, Charles (1989). "Anatomy of the Selection Problem". The Journal of Human Resources. 24 (3): 343–360. doi:10.2307/145818. JSTOR 145818.
- Manski, Charles (1990). "Nonparametric Bounds on Treatment Effects". The American Economic Review. 80 (2): 319–323. JSTOR 2006592.
- Marschak, Jacob; Andrews, Williams (1944). "Random Simultaneous Equations and the Theory of Production". Econometrica. 12 (3/4). The Econometric Society: 143–205. doi:10.2307/1905432. JSTOR 1905432.
- Powell, James (2017). "Identification and Asymptotic Approximations: Three Examples of Progress in Econometric Theory". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 31 (2): 107–124. doi:10.1257/jep.31.2.107.
- Lewbel, Arthur (2019-12-01). "The Identification Zoo: Meanings of Identification in Econometrics". Journal of Economic Literature. 57 (4). American Economic Association: 835–903. doi:10.1257/jel.20181361. ISSN 0022-0515. S2CID 125792293.
- Tamer, Elie (2010). "Partial Identification in Econometrics". Annual Review of Economics. 2 (1): 167–195. doi:10.1146/annurev.economics.050708.143401.
Further reading
[edit]- Ho, Kate; Rosen, Adam M. (2017). "Partial Identification in Applied Research: Benefits and Challenges" (PDF). In Honore, Bo; Pakes, Ariel; Piazzesi, Monika; Samuelson, Larry (eds.). Advances in Economics and Econometrics (PDF). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp. 307–359. doi:10.1017/9781108227223.010. ISBN 978-1-108-22722-3.
- Manski, Charles F.; Pepper, John V. (July 2000). "Monotone Instrumental Variables: With an Application to the Returns to Schooling" (PDF). Econometrica. 68 (4): 997–1010. doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00144 (inactive 22 December 2024). ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 2999533.
{{cite journal}}
: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of December 2024 (link) - Manski, Charles F. (2003). Partial Identification of Probability Distributions. New York: Springer-Verlag. ISBN 978-0-387-00454-9.